Eco-Watch Dialogues
8/10/99
To Fee or Not to Fee?
Dave Iverson
Over the past couple of years, the US Forest Service "Recreation Fee Demo Program" has kicked
off a firestorm of controversy. Or maybe it hasn't. It depends on who you
talk to. By some measures we are witnessing continued and wholesale transfer
of public interest to private. Those who believe this would say that it
started long ago with timbering, grazing, and mining and now has come down to
recreation -- what Scott Silver, Executive Director of Bend Oregon-based Wild Wilderness likes to call "Industrial Strength Wreckreation." By
other measures -- perspectives held by some Forest Service recreation staffers
and evidently by Forest Service top brass -- the Recreation Fee Demo Program
has broad public support and has elicited only a small flurry of negative comments.
The recreation fee demo program is an example of a policy issue where
deeply held public values are juxtaposed one against another in ways that most
of us, perhaps all of us, don't quite understand. Americans, at least some of
us, want access to our public land to be free, unencumbered by the type crass
commercialization that we face in most waking moments in our
capitalistic culture. On the other hand, we American's haven't been averse to
paying a small fee for developed campgrounds, even for entrance to some of the
National Parks. So what is the big deal about recreation user fees, if in
fact it is a big deal at all?
Short History of Fees and Fee Authority
Since its inception the US Forest Service has collected fees for some uses
while providing others uses free of charge, in an uneasy and continually
controversial mix of fee and free. Most of what has been administered using
fees -- commercial timber sales, grazing permits, special use permits for
outfitters, etc. -- has suffered criticism that fees are either too high or
too low (therefore subsidized) depending on which special interest sends the
message. Typically "preservationist" and
"environmentalist" groups send the message that commercial fees are
too low, while "commercialist" groups send the message that fees are
too high.
Much of what has been administered for free has suffered criticism too:
either that facilities are in disarray and/or that some special interests are
getting unfair advantage because their users can afford to use, or use more often, land,
buildings, boat launches, etc.that prove unaffordable to others who can not afford the means to even get to the forest yet alone to use facilities set up for those who have the automobiles, sport utility vehicles, boats, motorhomes, ATVs, etc. that the facilities were designed for.
Some people believe that historically certain special interest groups
have gained and held unfair advantage -- essentially privatizing public
interest for commercial gain -- in part by saying that they at least pay for
what they get as opposed to individuals, usually recreationists, who get their
private interests met without paying at all. Of course this leaves open the
argument as to whether it is appropriate to charge for commercial interest but
not for private interest. The foregoing reasoning is based only on
fairness and equity concerns regarding who pays and who benefits, and dismisses
entirely any notions of a common good that accrues from people spending time
in nature, far from the predominance of capital, markets, and particularly "marketing."
Prior to Congressional approval for "Recreation Fee Demo"
authority, Federal law prohibited charging fees for general access to national
forests. Fees could only be charged for use of "facilities," (i.e.
campgrounds, boat ramps, etc.). From this history, it seems clear that there
was a very conscious value/policy decision that the national forests were to
be a public commons, available to non-commercial users free of charge. The
ability to charge fees for grazing, timber harvesting, and commercial
recreation were specific statutory exceptions to the general rule that there
would be no access fee for the national forests. One would think that there is
some documented history concerning this provision of law. Whether or not such
documentation can be found, it seems likely that free access to public lands
was one of the many assurances provided to quell early opposition to the
general notion of a national forest system. If nothing more, the idea of
charging general admission fees is a radical departure from the early
intentions of the creators of the national forest system. So we must expect
that some will cry foul -- are crying foul -- at such a policy shift.
Recreation Fee Arguments Pro and Con
I've pulled together a few arguments "pro" and "con"
regarding recreation user fees. I hope that I've captured the main themes.
In Defense of Recreation User Fees:
- Fees are an increasingly popular new means to finance government, in
the "read my lips, no new taxes" era of government.
- Fees are a direct tax for use. People ought to pay for what they use.
- The US Forest Service has always relied on fees as part of its funding.
The agency was set up that way. Increasingly, timber and grazing fees don't
cut it in terms of funding extant organizational priorities -- timber fees
especially have been declining for two decades -- and new sources of funding are needed.
- Recreation fees might actually be a "final line of defense"
against the encroachment of "concessionaires" into the public
domain. This argument says that if we collect recreation fees the Forest
Service actually has the means to combat arguments that it is better to
"outsource" recreation concessions -- granting virtual monopoly
power to "concessionaires" and allowing further encroachment
through time -- perchance big business encroachment -- into the
"public" recreation domain.
- The US Park Service gets along arguably better than does the US Forest
Service -- at least in terms of having money to support recreation pursuits --
in part because they have a fee system in place for some of their most popular attractions.
In Opposition to Recreation User Fees:
- There is a long-standing tradition, religious and otherwise, of
"Forests Wild and Free" that militates against charging access fees.
One strain of this argument asks, "If we can walk free in our cities but
not in our forests, what is left of Wildness?"
- The American people and the Congress don't need yet another
bureaucratic cash cow and all the problems that entails as to "oversight
and accountability."
- It has been hard for the Forest Service and/or the Congress to regulate
big-business timber, mining, and grazing interests in the national forests.
Recreation fees help throw the doors open wide to embrace big-business
recreation interests, yet another big-business group, by condoning
"America for sale or rent" commercialization ideas, and promoting
"mechanically assisted recreation" that many in big-business favor.
- Environmental Justice problems loom large when recreation fees are
charged.
Fundamental Values Collide When Seeking to Impose General Access Fees
In the main two fundamental American traditions, and the values that underlie them, collide when we
speak of recreation fees charged for general access to the national
forests.
Americans value "capitalism." We are embedded in a culture founded in part on principles of capitalism,
private property, free enterprise, choice through the marketplace, and individual rights to use what one can pay for subject to
prohibitions imposed through law and custom.
Americans also value freedom from the marketplace in some aspects of our lives. Alongside our "capitalistic" cultural framing, we also have fundamental,
traditional American values to fulfill some public purposes through services
generally provided apart from the market. These include national defense,
police and fire protection, education (particularly primary and secondary
education), religion, use of public roadways, etc. We could append this list
with "public access to government lands," which have been provided
up to this point pretty much for free.
Like police and fire protection, there
are exceptional cases were individuals are charged for services on public
lands. Such "exceptional" charges are set up either to defray costs
of "above and beyond normal" expenses or as a deterrent to abuse of
systems provided at no direct cost to each individual or family. Obviously all
such services cost money, but tradition and custom have selectively set some
of them up apart from general market mechanisms.
When National Parks began charging access fees, a precedent was set to
begin to change one of these traditions. With US Forest Service recreation
fee demo authority, some argue that we are now experimenting with moving the line further
toward "capitalistic" traditions relative to "public lands access
for free" tradition. At a minimum any such policy shift tends to highlight value
clashes between these two dissimilar sets of values. No wonder at least some
people are intensely aggravated at the prospect of general recreation access fees.
There have
never been easy answers to the provision of services outside the market in
capitalistic/democratic systems. Some observers claim that the easy answer is
to "marketize" pretty much all but national defense. Some would
even "marketize" that. But others vehemently disagree and believe
that we've moved too far into the realm of markets already.
No Easy Answers
With democracy, there can be no easy answers to substantive value problems
where fundamental values are in conflict. In other systems of government there
may be easy answers but there are other problems -- most often relating to abuse of power. This particular
value clash over public access fees in the United States has been interesting,
if painful to watch. My point in this note is only to "name" the
conversation as one of values in conflict, and to suggest that each of the
warring factions has not to date given credit to the other for legitimate arguments
regarding American values. It continues to be "too bad" that we can
not have a civil conversation on this issue. Or maybe we all think that we are fulfilling our conversational needs vicariously through the many Rec Fee Demo News Articles on the subject and in the limited public forums where the issue has been aired. My personal feeling is that such fare fails any true test of dialogue and there are better ways to engage in conversation that have not yet been tried. Where it will end is anyone's guess right now.
If public lands access fees maintain their "toehold" at the
national level, and it must be admitted that a toehold is all they've got
right now, complications beyond "To Fee or Not to Fee" need to be
addressed. First, if fees are to be charged what will be the basis? There is
a long-standing tradition of subsidization, at least in the mind of many
observers, at the federal-level for traditional commodities: timber, grazing
forage, and minerals in particular.
If general or specific access fees
prevail, some recreationists will likely cry foul if they are charged what
they consider to be "fair market value" for access while commodity
interests continue on what these observers believe to be their
"normal" course of subsidization. So the Forest Service is likely
to have to grapple with this question for some time: "Why ought we to pay
$2 to $5 a day for access to the national forests when permittees pay $1.35
for a month's grazing for a cow?" And the Forest Service will continue
to grapple with the politically charged question, "Who ought to pay for
infrastructure, especially roads, and maintenance costs to mitigate
environmental damage."
At bottom, only one thing seems clear. When dealing
with questions of governance of public lands with both commercial and private users there are no easy answers. It gets even messier when we admit that most users are
also owners with deeply held, conflicting cultural values.
Index
Back to EcoWatch
Home Page